|
Reproduced with kind permission of the author from:
The INDEPENDENT REVIEW -
VOLUME 8 NUMBER 4 SPRING 2004
Abstract: Virtually every major social
pathology has been linked to
fatherless children: violent crime, drug and alcohol abuse,
truancy,
unwed pregnancy, suicide, and psychological disorders—all
correlating
more strongly with fatherlessness than with any other single
factor.
Tragically, however, government policies intended to deal
with the
“fatherhood crisis” have been ineffective at best
because the root
cause is not child abandonment by fathers but policies that
give
mothers an incentive to initiate marital separation and divorce.
During the past decade, family issues such
as marriage and fatherhood
have rocketed to the top of the domestic-policy agenda. The
past two
presidential administrations, along with numerous local governments,
have responded to the continuing crisis of the family by devising
measures to involve governmental machinery directly in the
management of what had previously been considered private
family life. The Bush administration has proposed $300 million
annually to “promote responsible fatherhood” and
for federal promotion of “healthy marriages.”
Earlier, President Bill Clinton created a “Presidential
Fatherhood Initiative,” and Vice President Al Gore chaired
a federal staff conference on “nurturing fatherhood.”
Congress has established bipartisan task forces on fatherhood
promotion and issued a resolution affirming the importance
of fathers. Almost 80 percent of the respondents to a 1996
Gallup poll saw fatherhood as the most serious social problem
today (NCF 1996).
A generation of fatherhood advocates has emerged
who insist that
fatherlessness is the most critical social issue of our time.
In Fatherless
America, David Blankenhorn calls the crisis of fatherless
children “the
most destructive trend of our generation” (1995, 1).
Their case is powerful. Virtually every major social pathology
has been linked to fatherless children: violent crime, drug
and alcohol abuse, truancy, unwed pregnancy, suicide, and
psychological disorders—all correlating more strongly
with fatherlessness than with any other single factor, surpassing
even race and poverty. The majority of prisoners, juvenile
detention inmates, high school dropouts, pregnant teenagers,
adolescent murderers, and rapists come from fatherless homes
(Daniels 1998, passim). Children from affluent but broken
families are much more likely to get into trouble than children
from poor but intact ones, and white children from separated
families are at higher risk than black children in intact
families (McLanahan 1998, 88). The connection between single-parent
households and crime is so strong that controlling for this
factor erases the relationship between race and crime as well
as between low income and crime (Kamarck and Galston 1990,
14).
Given these seemingly irrefutable findings,
a case might be made that both liberals and conservatives
should rethink their priorities. Rather than spending more
on antipoverty programs, as the left advocates, or on ever
harsher law enforcement, beloved of the right, both sides
should get together and help restore fatherhood as a solution
to social ills. On its surface, the government’s fatherhood
campaign seems to make good sense. As currently conceived,
however, it may be having precisely the opposite effect of
that advertised.
The policymakers’ discovery of fatherhood
has a disturbing side. In August 2002, Health and Human Services
(HHS) secretary Tommy Thompson announced mass arrests of parents
he says have disobeyed government orders, calling them the
“most wanted deadbeat parents.” The roundups were
carried out under a program started by the Clinton administration
called Project Save Our Children. The Clinton years saw repeated
and increasingly harsh measures against “deadbeat dads.”
The 1998 Deadbeat Parents Punishment Act was accompanied by
a “child support crackdown . . . to identify, analyze,
and investigate [parents] for criminal prosecution.”
HHS secretary Donna Shalala announced the Federal Case Registry
to monitor almost 20 million parents, whether or not they
had child-support arrearages, and the Directory of New Hires
database, which records the name of every newly hired individual
in the country (HHS 1998b).
Amid all this attention, little informed discussion
has occurred about the appropriate role of public policy with
respect to fatherhood and families. Marshalling federal agencies
to “promote” something as private and personal
as a parent’s relationship with his own children raises
questions. The assumption that the government has a legitimate
role in ameliorating the problem of fatherlessness also glides
quickly over the more fundamental question of whether the
government has had a role in creating the problem. What we
see in the “fatherhood crisis” may be an optical
illusion. What many are led to believe is a social problem
may in reality be an exercise of power by the state.
The conventional wisdom—enunciated by
political leaders, media commentators, and scholars—assumes
that the problem stems from paternal abandonment. Clinton
claimed that the fathers pursued by his administration “have
chosen to abandon their children” (1992). Blankenhorn
writes, “Today, the principal cause of fatherlessness
is paternal choice . . . the rising rate of paternal abandonment”
(1995, 22–23). David Popenoe, author of the essay “Life
Without Father,” writes that fathers “choose to
relinquish” the responsibilities of fatherhood (1998,
34). Yet none of these policymakers or writers cites any evidence
for this claim; in fact, no government or academic study has
ever shown that large numbers of fathers are abandoning their
children. Moreover, studies that answer the question directly
have arrived at a different conclusion.
In the largest federally funded study ever undertaken
on the subject, Arizona State University psychologist Sanford
Braver demonstrated that few married fathers voluntarily leave
their children. Braver found that overwhelmingly it is mothers,
not fathers, who are walking away from marriages. Moreover,
most of these women do so not with legal grounds such as abuse
or adultery but for reasons such as “not feeling loved
or appreciated.” The forcibly divorced fathers were
also found to pay virtually all child support when they are
employed and when they are permitted to see the children they
have allegedly abandoned
(1998, chap. 7).
Other studies have reached similar conclusions.
Margaret Brinig and Douglas Allen found that women file for
divorce in some 70 percent of cases. “Not only do they
file more often, but . . . they are more likely to instigate
separation.” Most significantly, the principal incentive
is not grounds such as desertion, adultery, or violence, but
control of the children. “We have found that who gets
the children is by far the most important component in deciding
who files for divorce” (2000, 126–27, 129, 158,
emphasis in original). One might interpret this statistic
to mean that what we call divorce has become in effect a kind
of legalized parental kidnapping.
Moreover, the vast machinery devoted to divorce
and custody litigation now has the power not only to seize
children whose parents have done nothing legally wrong, but
also to turn forcibly divorced parents into outlaws without
any wrong action on their part and in ways they are powerless
to avoid. What we are seeing today is nothing less than the
criminalization of parents, most often the fathers. A father
who is legally unimpeachable can be turned into a criminal
by the regime of involuntary divorce.
Partly responsible is “no-fault”
divorce, or what marriage advocate Maggie Gallagher terms
“unilateral” divorce, which allows one spouse
to abrogate the marriage contract without incurring any liability
for the consequences (1996, 143–52). “In all other
areas of contract law those who break a contract are expected
to compensate their partner or partners,” writes researcher
Robert Whelan, “but under a system of ‘no fault’
divorce, this essential element of contract law is abrogated”
(1995, 3). When children are involved, their separation from
one parent is then enforced by the state, with criminal penalties
against that parent for literally “no fault” of
his own.
We do not know precisely how many are affected.
Approximately 1.5 million divorces are granted annually in
the United States. Some studies predict 65 percent of marriages
will end in divorce. Some 80 percent of divorces are unilateral,
and the figure may be higher when children are involved in
approximately three-fifths of divorces. All told, more than
a million children become victims of divorce each year (Furstenberg
and Cherlin 1991, 22; Gallagher 1996, 5, 9, 22, 84–86;
Martin and Bumpass 1989). These figures imply that at least
700,000 parents are involuntarily divorced each year, and
control of their children is taken over by the government.
For all we can be certain, all 12–20 million parents
now being pursued as quasi-criminals by the federal government
have been separated involuntarily from their children through
no legal fault of their own (HHS 1998b; OCSEA 2001).
It is difficult to overestimate the importance
of this point, which contradicts the assumptions of policymakers
who call for repeated crackdowns on allegedly dissolute fathers.
“Children should not have to suffer twice for the decisions
of their parents to divorce,” Senator Mike DeWine declared
in June 1998, “once when they decide to divorce, and
again when one of the parents evades the financial responsibility
to care for them” (Congressional Record, June 5, 1998,
S5734). Yet most fathers and noncustodial mothers make no
such decision.
Punitive measures imposed on noncustodial parents
might be justifiable if, as is popularly believed (and as
government statements strongly imply), those parents were
deserting their families, giving legitimate grounds for divorce
or even agreeing to it. Parents who dissolve marriages arguably
give the state an interest in ensuring the well-being of their
children. It is not clear, however, what compelling public
interest justifies removing children from parents who do not
act to dissolve their marriages.
Some reply that even fathers whose children
are taken from them through no fault or agreement of their
own are still obliged to support them financially and to obey
other court orders. That all parents have a legal and moral
responsibility to care and provide for their children is not
at issue. The question not being asked, however, is why parents
charged with no civil or criminal wrongdoing must surrender
to the government the right to rear their own children. Requiring
an unimpeachable parent “to finance the filching of
his own children,” as attorney Jed Abraham puts it (1999,
151), encourages government officials to seize control of
the children, property, and persons of as many citizens as
they can, thereby increasing their jurisdiction and the demand
for their services.
For all the recent concern about both family
breakdown and judicial power, it is surprising that so little
attention is focused on family courts. They are certainly
the arm of government that routinely reaches deepest into
individuals and families’ private lives. “The
family court is the most powerful branch of the judiciary,”
according to Judge Robert Page of the New Jersey Family Court.
“The power of family court judges,” by their own
assessment, “is almost unlimited” (1993, 9, 11).
Supreme Court justice Abe Fortas once characterized them as
“kangaroo court[s]” (In Re Gault, 387 U.S. 1,
27–28 [1967]).
Very little information is available on these
courts. They usually operate behind closed doors and leave
no records. Statistics are virtually nonexistent because judges
and bar associations lobby to prevent the compilation of figures
(Levy, Gang, and Thompson 1997).
Most strikingly, they claim exemption from due
process of law and even from the Constitution itself. As one
father reports being told by the chief judicial investigator
in New Jersey, “The provisions of the U.S. Constitution
do not apply in domestic relations cases since they are determined
in a Court of Equity rather than [in a] Court of Law.”[1]
A connected rule known as the “domestic relations exception”
is said to justify the federal courts’ refusal to scrutinize
family-law cases for constitutional rights violations (60
U.S.L.W. 4532 [June 15, 1992]). A substantial body of federal
case law recognizes parenting as an “essential”
constitutional right “far more precious than property
rights” that “undeniably warrants deference, and,
absent a powerful countervailing interest, protection.”
This “fundamental liberty interest,” federal courts
have held, “cannot be denied without violating those
fundamental principles of liberty and justice which lie at
the base of all our civil and political institutions”
(Hubin 1999, 124). Yet divorce courts virtually never apply
such apparently unequivocal constitutional principles, and
the federal courts resist becoming involved.
A father brought before these courts is likely
to have only a few hours’ notice of a hearing that may
last thirty minutes or less, during which he will lose all
decision making authority over his children, be told when
and where he is authorized to see them, and ordered to begin
paying child support. His name will be entered on a federal
registry, his wages will immediately be garnished, and the
government will have access to all his financial information.
No allegations of wrongdoing, either civil or
criminal, are required. And no agreement to a divorce or separation
is necessary. Yet from this point, if he tries to see his
children outside the authorized times or fails to pay the
child support (or court ordered attorneys’ fees), he
will be subject to arrest.
A parent pulled into divorce court against his
will also must submit to questioning about his private life,
questioning that Abraham has characterized as an “interrogation.”
He can be forced to surrender personal diaries, correspondence,
financial records, and other documents normally protected
by the Fourth Amendment. His personal habits, movements, conversations,
writings, and purchases are subject to inquiry by the court.
His home can be entered by government agents. His visits with
his children can be monitored and restricted
to a “supervised visitation center.” Anything
he says to his spouse or children as well as to family counselors
and personal therapists can be used against him in court,
and his children can be used to inform on his compliance.
Fathers are asked intimate questions about how they “feel”
about their children, what they do with them, where they take
them, how they kiss them, how they feed and bathe them, what
they buy for them, and what they discuss with them. According
to Abraham, fathers against whom no evidence of wrongdoing
is presented are ordered to submit to “plethysmographs,”
a physical-response test in which an electronic sheath is
placed over the penis while the father is
forced to watch pornographic films of children (1999, 148,
58). A parent who refuses to cooperate can be summarily incarcerated
or ordered to undergo a psychiatric evaluation.
The parent from whom custody is removed no longer
has any say in where the children reside, attend school, or
worship. He has no necessary access to their school or medical
records or any control over medications or drugs. He can be
enjoined from taking his children to the doctor or dentist.
He can be told what religious services he may (or must) attend
with his children and what subjects he may discuss with them
in private.
In family court, it is not unusual for a father
earning $35,000 a year to amass $150,000 in attorney’s
fees, according to Washington attorney William Dawes. Unlike
any other debt, these fees may be collected by incarceration.
In fact, unlike the inmates in a medieval debtors’ prison,
he is punished even though he did not incur the debt voluntarily.
One of the most astonishing practices of family courts is
ordering fathers to pay the fees of attorneys, psychotherapists,
and other officials they have not hired and summarily jailing
them for not complying.
Family law is now criminalizing constitutionally
protected activities as basic as free speech, freedom of the
press, and even private conversations. In some jurisdictions,
it is a crime to criticize family-court judges or otherwise
to discuss family-law cases publicly, and fathers have been
arrested for doing so. Fathers who speak out against family
courts report that their children are used as weapons to silence
their dissent, and attorneys regularly advise their clients
not to join fathers’ rights groups, speak to the press,
or otherwise criticize
judges. Following his congressional testimony critical of
the family courts, Jim Wagner of the Georgia Children’s
Rights Council (CRC) was stripped of custody of his two children
and ordered to pay $6,000 in legal fees. When he could not
pay within fifteen days, the court jailed him.“We believe
. . . the court is attempting to punish Wagner for exposing
the court’s gender bias and misconduct to a congressional
committee,” said Sonny Burmeister, president of the
council (CRC 1992, 9). Though precluded by law from endorsing
political ideologies, the U.S. Department of Justice publishes
a paper by the National Council of Juvenile and Family Court
Judges, an association of ostensibly impartial judges who
sit on actual cases, that attacks fathers’ groups for
their “patriarchal values” and for advocating
“the rights of fathers instead of their responsibilities.”
The ostensibly apolitical judges ask, “How can we learn
to counter the sound bites of fathers’ rights groups?”
(qtd. in McHardy and Hofford 1999).
Like other state court judges, family-court
judges are either elected or appointed and are promoted by
commissions dominated by lawyers and other professionals (Tarr
1999, 61, 67, 69–70). These judges, in other words,
occupy political positions and are answerable to the bar associations
that naturally have an interest in maximizing the volume of
litigation (Corsi 1984, 107–14; Watson and Downing 1969,
98, 336). They also wield extensive powers of patronage that
enable them to force litigants to pay attorneys and expert
witnesses. These powers are not limited to family courts;
judges’ patronage powers have long been recognized (Jacob
1984, 112). Yet in no other courts has patronage so thoroughly
eclipsed justice. Although family courts, like most courts,
claim to be overburdened, it is clearly in their interest
to be overburdened because judicial powers and earnings are
determined by demand. As Judge Page explains, “Judges
and staff work on matters that are emotionally and physically
draining due to the quantity and quality of the disputes presented;
they should be given every consideration for salary and the
other ‘perks’ or other emoluments of their high
office. . . . With the improved status of judges and family-court
systems comes their proper position in judicial budgets as
worthy of appropriate funding” (1993, 19). Though caseloads
are large, the aim in improving the court’s status is
apparently to increase that load still further. If the judiciary
is viewed in part as a business, then the more satisfied the
customers—in this case, the bar associations and divorcing
parents who expect custody—the more customers will be
attracted. Again, in Judge Page’s words, “With
improved services more persons will come before the court
seeking their availability. . . . As the court does a better
job more persons will be attracted to it as a method of dispute
resolution. . . . The better the family-court system functions
the higher . . . the volume of the persons served” (1993,
20). In this view, the more attractive the courts make divorce
settlements for custodial parents, the more prospective custodial
parents will file for divorce and the more children will be
removed from, in most instances, their fathers.
A punitive quality seems to pervade the treatment
of fathers in general throughout divorce court, but the presumption
of guilt becomes explicit with accusations of spousal or child
abuse. Fathers accused of abuse during divorce are seldom
formally charged, tried, or convicted because there is usually
no evidence against them; hence, they never receive due process
of law or the opportunity to clear their names, let alone
recover their children. Yet the accusation alone prohibits
a father’s contact with his children and causes his
name to be entered into a national database of sex offenders
(Parke and Brott 1999, 49–50).
Although initial accusations do not necessarily
result in the father’s arrest, they do confirm his status
as a quasi-criminal whose movements are controlled by the
court. This control takes the form of an ex parte restraining
order, whose violation results in imprisonment. Orders separating
fathers from their children for months, years, and even life
are issued without the presentation of any evidence of wrongdoing.
They are often issued at a hearing at which the father is
not present and about which he may not even know, or they
may be issued over the telephone or by fax with no hearing
at all. A father receiving an order must vacate his residence
immediately and make no further contact with his children.
Boston attorney Elaine Epstein, former president
of the Massachusetts Women’s Bar Association, has written
that “allegations of abuse are now used for tactical
advantage” in custody cases and that restraining orders
are doled out “like candy.” “Restraining
orders and orders to vacate are granted to virtually all who
apply,” and “the facts have become irrelevant,”
she writes. “In virtually all cases, no notice, meaningful
hearing, or impartial weighing of evidence is to be had.”
Massachusetts judges alone issue some sixty thousand orders
each year (1993, 1).
Arresting fathers for attending public events
such as their children’s musical recitals or sports
activities—events any stranger may attend—is common.
In 1997, National Public Radio reported on a father arrested
in church for attending his daughter’s first communion.
During the segment, an eight-year-old girl wails and begs
to know when her father will be able to see or call her. The
answer, because of a lifetime restraining order, is never.
Even accidental contact in public places is punished with
arrest. New Jersey municipal court judge Richard Russell captured
the rationale in a 1994 judges’ training seminar: “Your
job is
not to become concerned about the constitutional rights of
the man that you’re violating as you grant a restraining
order. Throw [the man] out on the street, give him the clothes
on his back and tell him, see ya around. . . . They have declared
domestic violence to be an evil in our society. So we don’t
have to worry about the rights” (qtd. in Bleemer 1995,
1).
Some argue that judges must “balance”
the rights of accused men with the genuine need of women for
protection, yet we do not normally restrain citizens from
their basic constitutional rights, including the right of
free movement and free association (especially with their
own children) merely because someone asks us to do so. We
assume that all citizens are innocent until proven guilty,
that they have a right to due process of law, that they should
enjoy basic freedom until evidence of an infraction is presented
against them, and that knowingly false accusations will be
punished.
Some suggest that protective orders are issued
on the principle of “better safe than sorry,”
yet this suggestion begs the most telling question of how
protective orders can prevent violence, inasmuch as violence
is already illegal. A father whose wife obtained a restraining
order against him was, according to the St. Petersburg Times,
“enjoined and restrained from committing any domestic
violence upon her” (Schroeder and Sharp 1992, 2). Was
he, along with the rest of us, not so restrained to begin
with? The orders seem designed not so much to prevent wrongdoing
as to eliminate and criminalize fathers. Forcing a father
to stay away from his children even though he has done no
wrong may provoke precisely the kind of violent response it
ostensibly intends to prevent. “Few lives, if any, have
been saved, but much harm, and possibly loss of lives, has
come from the issuance of restraining orders and the arrests
and conflicts ensuing therefrom,” retired judge Milton
Raphaelson of the Dudley, Massachusetts, District Court writes.
“This is not only my opinion; it is the opinion of many
who remain quiet due to the political climate. Innocent men
and their children are deprived of each other” (2001,
4).
Connected here is the rapidly growing system
of government-funded visitation centers for which fathers
not necessarily convicted of any crime must pay as much as
$80 an hour to see their own children under the gaze of social
workers. “People yell at you in front of the children.
They try to degrade the father in the child’s eyes,”
the Massachusetts News quotes father Jim O’Brien in
August 1999. “I wish I’d never come here. . .
. They belittle you.” When O’Brien asked his daughter
if she’d made her first communion in the six years since
he had seen her, the social worker jumped in and said, “You’re
not allowed to ask that!” (Maguire 2000).
The practice of supervised visits is promoted
by the Supervised Visitation Network (SVN), a group whose
membership has mushroomed since its founding in 1992. The
“standards and guidelines” on SVN’s Internet
site make clear that supervised visitation is not limited
to cases of violence or potential violence by the noncustodial
parent against the children, which it clearly regards as exceptional,
but is appropriate in any circumstances of “conflict”
between parents. SVN defines family violence to include matters
that are not physical or illegal or, indeed, violent: “Family
violence is any form of physical, sexual, or other abuse inflicted
on any person in a household by a family or household member”
(SVN 2001, emphasis added).
Domestic violence is now a major industry funded
through interlocking government programs at the federal, state,
and local levels and by private foundations and international
organizations. The premise on which this industry is largely
based— that domestic violence is a political crime perpetrated
exclusively by men against women— has already been refuted
by many studies that show that men and women commit domestic
violence at roughly equally rates, so it requires no further
treatment here (Fiebert 1997; Straus forthcoming). In a legal
sense, of course, it does not matter what percentage of domestic
violence is committed by which sex because the important issue
is due rocess of law for every individual. Yet the very recognition
of a special category of “domestic violence,”
separate from other forms of assault—a category defined
by the private relationship between the parties rather than
by the nature of their actions—blurs the distinction
between crime and noncriminal personal conflict.
The power to criminalize nonviolent private
behavior, personal imperfections, and routine family disagreements
is conveyed concisely in the term abuse, which is ambiguous
and elastic enough to be stretched beyond what is usually
considered physical and criminal. “You do not have to
be hit to be abused” is now a standard line in the abuse
literature. Abuse can be defined as “criticizing you
for small things” and “making you feel bad about
yourself.” Criminal justice agencies now accept these
definitions in official publications. The National Victim
Assistance Academy, a project funded by the U.S. Department
of Justice and published on its Internet site, includes such
items as “extreme jealousy and possessiveness,”
“name calling and constant criticizing,” and “ignoring,
dismissing, or ridiculing the victim’s needs”
in its chapter on domestic violence (Coleman et al. 2000).
By these criteria, violence becomes whatever the alleged victim
says it is. In her influential book The Battered Woman, psychologist
Lenore Walker excuses a woman who violently attacked her husband
because he “had been battering her by ignoring her and
by working late” (1979, xv).
What matters here is to what degree this domestic
violence hysteria is aimed specifically at removing children
from their fathers. There is reason to believe that this objective
is the main thrust behind it. Feminists point out that most
domestic violence occurs during “custody battles”
and that the vast preponderance of domestic violence takes
place among divorced and separated couples (Rennison and Welchans
2000, 4–5). Susan Sarnoff of Ohio State University points
out that the Violence Against Women Act II, passed by Congress
in 2000, not only legitimizes the making of knowingly false
accusations, “but . . . offers abundant rewards for
doing so—including the ‘rights’ to refuse
custody and even visitation to accused fathers—with
virtually no requirements of proof.” Moreover, “the
bill’s definition of domestic violence . . . is so broad
that it does not even require that the violence be physical”
(1998, 1, 12).
The most serious effect of forcibly removing
fathers after quasi-criminal accusations is the abuse of children
it induces. Contrary to popular belief, it is not fathers,
but mothers—especially single mothers—who are
most likely to abuse children. An HHS study found that women
ages twenty to forty-nine are almost twice as likely as men
to be perpetrators of child maltreatment: “It is estimated
that . . . almost twothirds [of child abusers] were females”
(HHS 1998a, xi–xii). Given that male perpetrators are
not necessarily fathers but more likely to be boyfriends and
stepfathers, fathers emerge as the least likely child abusers.
Researcher Robert Whelan found that children are as much as
thirty-three times more likely to be abused when a live-in
boyfriend or stepfather is present (1993, 29). And “[c]ontrary
to public perception,” write Patrick Fagan and Dorothy
Hanks of the Heritage Foundation, “the most likely physical
abuser of a young child will be that child’s mother,
not a male in the household” (1997, 16). Mothers accounted
for 55 percent of child murders, according to a 1994 Justice
Department report, whereas fathers were responsible for only
a relatively tiny percentage (BJS 1994). From the father’s
perspective, it appears that the real abusers have removed
him from the family so they can abuse his children with impunity.
Fatherhood advocate Adrienne Burgess writes that “fathers
have often played the protector role inside families”
(Burgess 1997, 54). This claim is confirmed by academic research,
however diffident scholars may be about saying so. “The
presence of the father . . . placed the child at lesser risk
for child sexual abuse,” concludes a study of low-income
families. “The protective effect from the father’s
presence in most households was sufficiently strong to offset
the risk incurred by the few paternal perpetrators”
(Rowland, Zabin, and Emerson 2000).
Not only has this protective role become ideologically
incorrect, but it may also criminalize the father. Such violence
by men as does occur may be more often the result than the
cause of fathers’ losing their children; common sense
suggests that fathers with no previous proclivity to violence
might well erupt when their children are taken from them.
“A significant percentage of domestic violence occurs
during litigated divorces in families who never had a history
of it,” according to Douglas Schoenberg, a New Jersey
divorce attorney and mediator (qtd. in Braver 1998, 240).
Anne McMurray of Australia’s Griffith University found
that domestic violence usually arose “during the process
of marital separation and divorce, particularly in relation
to disputes over child custody, support, and access.”
McMurray’s subjects describe how violence “had
not been a feature of the marriage but had been triggered
by the separation” (1997, 543, 547).
Violent attacks against judges and lawyers are
also usually connected with custody litigation. “Judges
and lawyers nationwide agree . . . that family law is the
most dangerous area in which to practice,” reports the
California Law Week (McKee 1999). The year 1992 was “one
of the bloodiest in divorce court history—a time when
angry and bitter divorce litigants declared an open season
on judges, lawyers, and the spouses who brought them to court”
(Cheever 1992, 29). Dakota County, Minnesota, district attorney
James Backstrom says family court produces far more violence
than criminal court does: “We’re most concerned
about the people in family court—the child support and
divorce cases” (qtd. in Worden 2000). The Boston Globe
reports that some judges now carry guns under their robes
to protect themselves not from criminals but from fathers
(McGrory 1994, 33). In December 1998, the ABC television magazine
20/20 also reported on this phenomenon. No father was quoted,
but fathers generally were portrayed as little better than
dangerous animals. One of the many lawyers interviewed comments,
“You really don’t know what monsters lurk behind
regular people.” It ought hardly to surprise anyone
that interfering with their children is one way to find out.
As noted earlier, noncustodial parents can be
arrested for unauthorized contact with their children, but
the criminalization of most fathers takes place through the
childsupport system. A parent who loses custody must pay child
support to the parent who wins custody. This assignment has
the tendency to turn children into cash prizes. In fact, it
exerts a similar effect on the government, for the money passes
through the state treasury, where it is used to earn federally
funded bonuses for the state. According to the Deadbeat Parents
Punishment Act, if for any reason the parent falls more than
$5,000 behind, he becomes a felon. Theoretically, he can become
an instant felon as soon as he loses his children. If the
ordered payments are high enough and backdated to exceed the
$5,000 threshold, he will be subject to immediate arrest,
even before he has had an opportunity to pay.
A father charged with “civil contempt”
connected with child support may be exempted from due process
of law and legally presumed guilty until proven innocent.
“The burden of proof may be shifted to the defendant,”
according to a legal analysis by the National Conference of
State Legislatures (NCSL), an organization that encourages
aggressive prosecutions. The father can also be charged with
criminal contempt, for which in theory he must be duly tried,
but in fact sometimes is not. “The lines between civil
and criminal contempt are often blurred in failure to pay
child support cases,” the NCSL continues.
“Not all child support contempt proceedings classified
as criminal are entitled to a jury trial.” Further,
“even indigent obligors are not necessarily entitled
to a lawyer.” Thus, a father who has lost his children
through literally no fault of his own can be arrested and
required to prove his innocence without a formal charge, without
counsel, and without a jury of his peers (Myers n.d.).
As noted earlier, fathers who allegedly fail
to pay child support—“deadbeat dads” —are
now the subjects of a national demonology, officially designated
villains whose condign punishment is applauded by politicians,
press, and public alike. Yet the reality is somewhat different.
Scholars have already challenged the deadbeat dad stereotype,
so it requires only brief treatment here. Braver
found that government claims of nonpayment are produced not
from any compiled data (which do not exist), but simply from
surveys of custodial parents. Like others, he concluded that
“the single most important factor relating to nonpayment”
is unemployment (1998, 21–22 and chap. 2).
Revolving doors and other channels connect family courts with
executive branch enforcement bureaucracies. David Ross, head
of federal child-support enforcement in the Clinton administration,
began his career as a family-court judge before moving on
to higher courts and a stint in a state legislature. The 2001
web page of the federal Office of Child Support Enforcement
(OCSE) said he was honored as “Judge of the Year of
America” by the National Reciprocal Family Support Enforcement
Association in 1983 and as “Family Court Judge of the
Nation” by the National Child Support Enforcement Association
[NCSEA] in 1989.” The fact that enforcement agents are
bestowing honors on supposedly impartial and apolitical judges
indicates the agents’ interest in family-court decisions,
primarily the decisions to remove children from their fathers
and then to award the punitive child support that necessitates
their services. That a government
Internet page would boast about awards given to its officials
by pressure groups tiny these connections receive. The NCSEA
web
page describes its members as “state and local agencies,
judges, court masters, hearing officers, district attorneys,
government and private attorneys, social workers, caseworkers,
advocates, and other child support professionals,” as
well as “corporations that partner with government to
enforce child support” (NCSEA 2001). In other words,
it includes officials from at least two branches of government
and members of the private sector who have a financial interest
in separating children from their fathers.
Setting child-support levels is a political process conducted
by pressure groups involved in divorce but from which parents
who pay the support are largely excluded. Approximately half
the states use guidelines devised not by the legislature but
by courts and enforcement agencies, and in all states these
officials have a dominant role (Morgan 1998, table 1-2). Under
the separation of powers, we normally do not permit police
and courts to make the laws they enforce and interpret because
doing so would create an obvious conflict of interest for
those with a stake in having criminals to prosecute. At the
same time, legislative enactment is no guarantee of impartiality
because legislators can divert enforcement contracts to their
own firms. An extreme example led to federal racketeering
convictions of Arkansas state legislators in 2000.
Provisions for citizen input appear perfunctory
for the most part. Virginia requires legislative enactment,
but its review of its child-support guidelines in 1999 was
conducted by a commission that included one part-time representative
of parents paying child support and ten employed full-time
by agencies and organizations that benefit directly from divorce
(Koplen 1999, 4). “The commissions appointed
to review the guidelines have been composed, in large part,
of individuals who are unqualified to assess the economic
validity of the guidelines, or who arguably have an interest
in maintaining the status quo, or both,” writes Georgia
district attorney William Akins. “In 1998 . . . of the
11 members of that Commission, two were members of the judiciary,
two represented custodial parent advocacy groups, four were
either present or former child support enforcement personnel
and two were state legislators” (2000, 12). In a case
involving a noncustodial mother, a Georgia superior court
agreed with this assessment, declaring the state’s guidelines
unconstitutional on “numerous” grounds. “The
guidelines bear no relationship to the constitutional standards
for child support of requiring each parent to have an equal
duty in supporting the child” and create “a windfall
to the obligee.” Characterizing the guidelines as “contrary
both to public policy and common sense,” the court noted
that they bear no connection to the cost of rearing children.
“The custodial parent does not contribute to child costs
at the same rate as the non-custodial parent and, often, not
at all,” the court noted. “The presumptive award
leaves the non-custodial parent in poverty while the custodial
parent enjoys a notably higher standard of living” (Georgia
DHR v. Sweat, Georgia Supreme Court, no. SO3A0179 [April 29,
2003]). A Tennessee court likewise struck down that state’s
child-support guidelines as violating the equal protection
clause of the Constitution. The Tennessee Department of Human
Services, which regularly jails fathers for minor violations
of court orders, announced it would ignore the court’s
ruling (Gallaher v. Elam, Tennessee Appeals Court, no. E2000-02719-COA-R3-CV
[January 29, 2002]).
The conflicts of interest appear even more clearly
in the private sector. Child support enforcement is now a
$5 billion national industry in terms of the money expended;
in terms of the money it aims to collect, it is a multi-billion-dollar
enterprise. Privatization has created a class of government-subsidized
bounty hunters with a financial interest in creating “delinquents.”
In 1998, Florida taxpayers paid $4.5 million to Lockheed Martin
IMS and Maximus, Inc., to collect $162,000 from fathers (Parker
1999). Supportkids of Austin, Texas, describes
itself as “the privatesector leader” in what it
calls the “child support industry.” The company
is confident of rich investment opportunities in coming years,
optimistic that delinquencies will only increase. “The
market served totals $57 billion and is growing at an annual
rate of $6 billion to $8 billion per year,” reports
a company press release on March 13, 2000. “There is
a huge market for the private sector to serve” (Supportkids
2000). The size of this “market” is determined
not by demand from sovereign consumers but by how many parents
can be forcibly separated from their children and criminalized
by forced
debts that are “contrary to common sense,” as
the Georgia superior court judge put it.
The debts have been set indirectly by the very companies that
collect them. From 1983 to 1990, Dr. Robert Williams, later
president of Policy Studies Inc. (PSI), was a paid consultant
with HHS, where he helped to establish uniform state guidelines
in the federal Child Support Guidelines Project under a grant
from the National Center for State Courts. He also consults
directly with many states. During this time, “a federally-driven
approach . . . significantly increased child support obligations,”
according to James Johnston, a member of the Kansas Child
Support Guidelines Advisory Committee. Congress also passed
the Family Support Act of 1988, requiring states to implement
presumptive guidelines and giving them only a few months of
legislative time
to do so (Rogers and Bieniewicz 2000, 2, 5). Virtually all
states met the
deadline, many by quickly adopting Williams’s model.
“The guidelines were enacted in 1989 to insure [sic]
Georgia’s receipt of an estimated $25 million in federal
funds,” writes Akins (2000).
One year after joining HHS and the same year
the mandatory federal guidelines were implemented, Williams
started PSI. “With his inside knowledge [Williams] has
developed a consulting business and collection agency targeting
privatization opportunities with those he has consulted,”
Johnston explains. “In 1996, his company had the greatest
number of child support enforcement contracts
. . . of any of the private companies that held state contracts”
(1999). The Denver Business Journal reports that PSI grew
“by leaps and bounds because of the national crackdown
on ‘deadbeat dads.’” From three employees
in 1984, it expanded rapidly to more than five hundred in
1996, before welfare reform legislation took effect, by which
the company “stands to profit even more” (Mook
1997).
Yet more serious than the profiteering is the
level of obligation. A collection agency profits only if there
are arrearages. Not only does Williams have an interest in
making the child-support levels as high as possible to increase
his share overall, but he also must make them high enough
to create hardship, arrearages, and “delinquents.”
Williams’s model has been widely and severely
criticized for its methodology (Rogers 1999). He himself has
acknowledged that “there is no consensus among economists
on the most valid theoretical model to use in deriving estimates
of child-rearing expenditures” and that “use of
alternative models yields widely divergent estimates.”
Donald Bieniewicz, member of an advisory panel to the OCSE,
comments, “This [statement] is a shocking vote of ‘no
confidence’ in the . . . guideline by its author”
(1999, 2). Yet on the basis of Williams’s guideline,
parents are being jailed, usually without trial.
Governments, too, can reap substantial profits
from child support. “Most states make a profit on their
child support program,” according to the House Ways
and Means Committee, which notes that “states are free
to spend this profit in any manner the state sees fit.”
States profit largely through federal incentive payments,
as well as by receiving two-thirds of operating costs and
90 percent of computer costs (U.S. House of Representatives
1998).To collect these funds, states must channel payments
through their criminal enforcement machinery, further criminalizing
the fathers and allowing the
government to claim that its enforcement measures are increasing
collections despite the consistent operating loss in the federal
program. In January 2000, Secretary Shalala announced that
“the federal and state child support enforcement program
broke new records in nationwide collections in fiscal year
1999, reaching $15.5 billion, nearly doubling the amount collected
in 1992” (HHS 2000). Yet the method of arriving at these
figures is questionable.
When we hear of collections through enforcement agencies,
we assume they involve arrearages or that they target those
who do not otherwise pay and whose compliance must be “enforced.”
In 1992, most child support was still being paid voluntarily
and directly, without coercion or accounting by the state.
Increasingly over the past decade, all payments (including
current ones) have been routed through enforcement agencies
by automatic wage garnishing and other coercive measures that
presume criminality. Moreover, OCSE figures show that whereas
the number of welfare-related cases (where collection is
difficult) has remained steady since 1994, the number of nonwelfare
cases (where compliance is high) has steadily increased (OCSE
1999, 4). The “increase” in collections was achieved
not by collecting the alleged arrearages built up by poor
fathers already in the criminal collection system, but rather
by bringing in more employed middle-class fathers who pay
faithfully. The payments and the accounting mechanism also
provide additional incentives to squeeze as many dollars out
of as many fathers as possible and have the added effect of
further institutionalizing their status as semicriminals.
Advocates of unilateral divorce portray it as
a “citizen’s right” and a “civil liberty,”
yet in practice the regime of involuntary divorce has led
to authoritarian measures against forcibly divorced parents
and others. Some sixty thousand government agents, some of
them armed, now enforce child support, approximately thirteen
times the worldwide number of Drug Enforcement Administration
agents.
These plainclothes police now command sweeping
powers to seize property and persons involved involuntarily
in divorce proceedings, including the power to issue arrest
warrants. They also have powers to gather information on private
citizens unknown to other officials. Hunting alleged deadbeats
even rationalizes the monitoring of citizens who have no connection
with child support. In addition to automatic wage garnishing
of all obligors even before they become delinquent,
the New Hires Directory now compels employers to furnish the
names of all new employees to the federal government. “Never
before have federal officials had the legal authority and
technological ability to locate so many Americans found to
be delinquent parents—or such potential to keep tabs
on Americans accused of nothing,” reported the Washington
Post (O’Harrow 1999, A1). “Just like in totalitarian
societies, government bureaucrats will soon have the power
to deny
you a job, and the ability to monitor your income, assets,
and debts,” said Libertarian Party chairman Steve Dasbach
in a 1998 press release. “This law turns the presumption
of innocence on its head and forces every American to prove
their innocence to politicians, bureaucrats, and computers”
(Dasbach 1998). At least one state government has dissented.
“Under the guise of cracking down on so-called deadbeat
dads, the Congress has required the states to carry out a
massive and intrusive federal regulatory scheme by which personal
data on all state citizens” is collected, the Kansas
attorney general’s office charged in a federal suit
challenging the mandate’s constitutionality (qtd. in
Boczkiewicz 2000). Echoing a term used by fathers’ groups,
one Kansas legislator called the federal directives extortion,
and colleagues in Nebraska described them as “a form
of blackmail” (Christensen 2001, 69).
The line between the guilty and the innocent
becomes unclear because officials track not only parents with
arrearages, but also those whose payments are current and
those who are not under any order at all. (At one point, former
attorney general Janet Reno referred to even noncustodial
parents who do pay as “deadbeats” [DOJ 1994].)
One agent expressed the presumption of guilt, boasting to
the Washington Post, “We don’t give them an opportunity
to become deadbeats” (O’Harrow 1999, A1). The
NCSL points to the presumptions
not only that all parents under child-support orders are already
quasi-criminals, but also that all citizens are potential
criminals against whom preemptive enforcement measures must
be initiated now in anticipation of their future criminality.
“Some people have argued that the state should only
collect the names of child support obligors, not the general
population,” they suggest. But “this argument
ignores the primary reason” for collecting the names:
“At one point or another, many people will either be
obligated to pay or eligible to receive child support”
(Top 5 Questions).
Between the incentive payments, the patronage,
and the bureaucratic conflicts of interest, aggressive collection
methods now seem to be the norm rather than the exception.
Perhaps most disturbing is the case of Brian Armstrong of
Milford, New Hampshire, who some claim received a summary
“death sentence” for losing his job. Armstrong
was jailed without trial in January 2000 for missing a hearing
about which his family claims he was never notified. One week
later he was dead,
apparently from a beating by correctional officials.[2]
Fatal beatings of fathers are probably not widespread
in North American jails, but other fatalities exemplify a
more common form of “death penalty” routinely
meted out to fathers who are neither charged with nor tried
for any crime. In March 2000, Darrin White of Prince George,
British Columbia, was denied all contact with his three children,
evicted from his home, and ordered to pay more than twice
his income as well as court costs in a divorce for which he
gave neither grounds nor agreement. White hanged himself from
a tree.[3]
In contrast to Armstrong’s fate, White’s
seems to be common. “There is nothing unusual about
this judgment,” said former British Columbia Supreme
Court judge Lloyd McKenzie, who pointed out that the judge
in White’s case applied standardized child-support guidelines
(Lee 2000). The suicide rate of divorced fathers has skyrocketed,
according to Augustine Kposowa of the University of California.
Kposowa (2000) attributes his finding directly to judgments
from family courts.
Throughout the United States and abroad, child-support
machinery has been beset with allegations of mismanagement
and corruption (Baskerville 2003). In Colorado, “the
results of a new audit showed that the state’s child
support enforcement system is in disarray” (Franke-Folstad
1999), according to those involved in the process. “It’s
not like it’s gone from good news to bad news. It’s
just worse news, ” says Richard Hoffman of the organization
Child Support Enforcement (qtd. in Franke- Folstad 1999).
According the Weekly Wire, “Tennessee, like many states
around the country, has recently begun pursuing deadbeat parents
with a new level of determined vengeance.” Yet the state
collection agency’s own Child Support Fact Sheet indicates
that Tennessee actually “collected less in child support
per dollar of state expenditure in fiscal year 1997 than it
has in any of the preceding four years during which this indicator
has steadily trended negatively” (Granju 1998; see also
Loggins 2001). The Aurora Beacon News in Illinois reported
on October 16, 1999, that “a new state child support
processing system . . . has delayed payments to thousands
of parents,” and mothers are refusing to let children
see their fathers “under the belief that the parents
responsible for child support haven’t made their payments”
(Olsen 1999).
In Britain, the London Times editorialized in
1999 that the nation’s Child Support Agency had become
“a monstrous bureaucracy, chasing responsible parents
and wrecking the families it was meant to support.”
As elsewhere, the directors promise a “thorough overhaul,”
yet with uncertain logic place the blame not on the government
but on the “responsible parents” whose families
it is wrecking: “In future, absent fathers will have
to prove they are not the father of a child,”
reported the Times, apparently oblivious to the contradiction
(Father Figures 1999). In Australia, a 2000 parliamentary
inquiry into the Child Support Agency (CSA) found “systemic
corruption by public servants.” Robert Kelso of Central
Queensland University reports “evidence the CSA is .
. . creating false debt by exaggerating incomes of fathers.”
Commission chairman Roger Price said no one should have any
illusions that the CSA was set up to benefit children: “It
is not about the best interests of children and never has
been” (Kelso and Price qtd. in Stapleton 2000, 26).
Current enforcement practice overturns centuries of common
law precedent that a father could not be forced to pay for
the stealing of his own children. “The duty of a father
(now spouse) to support his children is based largely upon
his right to their custody and control,” runs one court
ruling typical of the age-old legal consensus. “A father
has the right at Common Law to maintain his children in his
own home, and he cannot be compelled against his will to do
so elsewhere,
unless he has refused or failed to provide for them where
he lives” (Butler v. Commonwealth, 132.Va.609, 110 S.E.
868 [1922]). As recently as 1965, the Oregon Supreme Court
held that “a husband whose wife left him without cause
was not required to support his children living with her”
and that “parents generally may decide, free from government
supervision, at what level and by what means they will support
their children” (qtd. in Harris, Waldrop, and Waldrop
1990, 711, 689).
Today, these precedents are ignored, so much
so that a father becomes a “deadbeat” if he fails
or refuses to surrender control of his children to the government
hegemony. “Child support is ‘paid’ only
when it’s paid in a bureaucratically acceptable form,”
writes Bruce Walker of the District Attorney’s Council
in Oklahoma City, who claims to have jailed hundreds of fathers.
“Men who provide nonmonetary support are deadbeat dads
according to the child-support system,” says Walker.
“Even men who are raising in their homes the very children
for whom child support is sought are deadbeat dads. If the
mother gives the father the children because she cannot control
them or has other problems, then he is still liable for child
support” (1996, 18).
Fathers who lose their jobs are seldom able
to hire lawyers to have their childsupport payment lowered,
and judges rarely lower it anyway. Yet government lawyers
will prosecute a father free of charge, regardless of his
or the mothers’ income. It is also now a federal crime
for a father who is behind in child support, for whatever
reason, to leave his state, even if doing so is his only way
to find work. This law has even been used to prosecute a father
whose former wife moved to another state with his children
(Parke and Brott, 64–65).
Why so many divorced fathers seem to be unemployed
or penurious may be accounted for by the strains that legal
proceedings place on their emotions and work schedules. Many
fathers are summoned to court so often that they lose their
jobs, whereupon they can be jailed for being unemployed. Many
divorced fathers are either ordered out of their homes or
must move out for financial reasons, so they are immediately
homeless. They may also lose their cars, which may be their
only transportation to their jobs and children. Those who
fall behind in child support, regardless of the reason, have
their cars booted and their driver’s licenses and professional
licenses revoked, which in turn prevents them from getting
and keeping employment. An odd myopia is demonstrated in a
controversy over whether to give child support priority over
other debts during bankruptcy, when no one seems willing to
ask the obvious question of why large numbers
of allegedly well-heeled deadbeats are going through bankruptcy
in the first place (U.S. House of Representatives 1998). A
Rutgers and University of Texas study found that “many
of the absent fathers who[m] state leaders want to track down
and force to pay child support are so destitute that their
lives focus on finding the next job, next meal or next night’s
shelter” (Edin, Lein, and Nelson
1998). In what some have termed a policy of “starvation,”
a proposed federal regulation will render these impecunious
playboys ineligible for food stamps (Federal Register, 64
FR 70919, December 17, 1999).
Though ostensibly limited by guidelines, a judge
may order virtually any amount in child support. If a judge
decides that a father could be earning more than he does,
the judge can “impute” potential income to the
father and assess child support and legal fees based on that
imputed income. The result is that child- support payments
can exceed what the father actually earns. If a father at
any point works extra hours (perhaps to pay attorneys’
fees) or receives other temporary income, he is then locked
into that income and those hours and into
the child-support level based on them. If a relative or benefactor
pays the child support on his behalf, that payment is considered
a “gift” and does not offset the obligation that
the father still owes. If the payment is made to the father,
it becomes “income,” which is then used to increase
his monthly obligation.
It is hardly surprising that some fathers who have been through
this ordeal eventually do disappear. Anyone who has been plundered,
vilified, and incarcerated—all on the claim of supporting
children who have been taken away from him through no fault
of his own—will eventually reach the limits of his endurance.
Some may be tempted to conclude that this outcome is precisely
what the enforcement system is designed to encourage, for
certainly it does no harm to the enforcers’ business.
The relentless (il)logic of the child-support
system extends up to the level of federal policy, to the point
where the tail seems to wag the dog. Although new federal
programs claim to “promote fatherhood” and “enhance
relationships,” no explanation is forthcoming from HHS
of how precisely the government can achieve these objectives.
What requires no explanation is that the government can arrest
and incarcerate people, which seems to be what it is doing
to those whose marriages it is unable to save.
In May 2003, HHS announced grants to “faith-based
groups.” In Idaho, Healthy Families Nampa (whose name
seems tailored to the federal program) will use $544,400 for
“counseling and other supportive services to parents
who are interested in marrying each other,” Assistant
Secretary Wade Horn told the Associated Press. Horn said the
grants are “targeted at preventing divorce among those
who are married and at improving parenting skills of both
married and non-married couples” (qtd. in Meckler 2003).
HHS documents make clear,
however, that in fact the grants are for collecting child
support. Michigan’s enforcement agency will receive
almost a million dollars above its regular federal subsidies.
Horn claimed the aim is to “enhance the overall goals
and effectiveness of the child support enforcement program
by integrating the promotion of healthy marriage into existing
child support services” (HHS 2003). He did not explain
how law enforcement agents can enhance anyone’s marriage.
Evidence suggests that these agents are having
precisely the opposite
effect. Bryce Christensen of the Howard Center for Family,
Religion, and
Society points to “evidence of the linkage between aggressive
child-support policies and the erosion of wedlock” because
child-support enforcement subsidizes divorce. The latest moves
by HHS seem to validate Christensen’s conclusion. “Politicians
who have framed such [child-support] policies . . . have—however
unintentionally—actually reduced the likelihood that
a growing number of children will enjoy the tremendous economic,
social, and psychological benefits which the realization of
that ideal [of a two-parent family] can bring” (2001,
67, 63).
Here we have the ingredients of a government
perpetual-growth machine, one that extends well beyond family
policy. Identifying fathers rather than governments as the
culprits behind family dissolution not only justifies harsh
law enforcement measures, but also rationalizes policies that
contribute further to the absence of fathers, which they ostensibly
are meant to prevent. Further—given the undeniable correlation
that the fatherhood advocates have established between fatherlessness
and today’s larger social pathologies, such as poverty,
crime, and substance abuse—it allows officials to ignore
the
simplest and safest solution to these ills, which is to stop
eliminating fathers. Instead, governments devise elaborate
schemes, invariably extending their reach and power, to deal
with the problems that their removal of the fathers has created:
not only fatherhood promotion and marriage therapy, but larger
antipoverty programs beloved of the left and law enforcement
measures dear to the right. By concocting a fatherhood crisis
where none previously existed , government across the spectrum
has neutered the principal rival to its power and created
an unlimited supply of problems for itself to solve.
1. Standard legal authorities insist this distinction
no longer exists. “With the procedural merger of law
and equity in the federal and most state courts, equity courts
have been abolished” (Black’s Law Dictionary,
6th ed., s.v. “Equity, courts of”). back
2. West 2000, and accompanying accounts by and
interviews with Armstrong’s family. The U.S. Attorney’s
office in Concord, New Hampshire, has refused to discuss the
case. back
3. Account compiled from interviews with White’s
daughter and with Todd Eckert of the Parent and Child Advocacy
Coalition, who was assisting White before his death, and from
reports by Donna Laframboise in the National Post, March 23,
25, and 27, 2000, in the Vancouver Sun, March 24, 2000, and
in the Ottawa Citizen, March 24 and 27, 2000. Attacks on White
in the Toronto Sun (April 9,
2000) and in other newspapers did not contest the essential
facts. back
Abraham, Jed. 1999. From Courtship to Courtroom:
What Divorce Law Is Doing
to Marriage. New York: Bloch.
Akins, William. 2000. Why Georgia’s Child
Support Guidelines Are Unconstitutional.
Georgia Bar Journal 6, no. 2: 8–14, 54–57. Also
available at:
http://www.economic-indicators.com/GABarJourAkins.htm.
Baskerville, Stephen. 2003. The Politics of
Child Support. PS: Political Science
and Politics 36, no. 4: 719–20.
Bieniewicz, Donald. 1999. Improving State Child
Support Guidelines. Testimony
to the Virginia Child Support Quadrennial Review Panel. Available
at: http://www.guidelineeconomics.com/files/VA_Bieniewicz1999.pdf.
Blankenhorn, David. 1995. Fatherless America:
Confronting Our Most Urgent
Social Problem. New York: Basic.
Bleemer, Russ. 1995. N.J. Judges Told to Ignore
Rights in Abuse TROs. New
Jersey Law Journal 140 (April 24): 1–14.
Boczkiewicz, Robert. 2000. State Fighting Feds
in Appeals Court. Topeka
Capital-Journal, January 22. Available at: http://www.cjonline.com/stories/012200/kan_appealscrt.shtml.
Braver, Sanford. 1998. Divorced Dads: Shattering
the Myths. New York:
Tarcher/Putnam.
Brinig, Margaret, and Douglas W. Allen. 2000.
These Boots Are Made for
Walking: Why Most Divorce Filers are Women. American Economics
and
Law Review 2, no. 1: 126–69.
Bureau of Justice Statistics (BJS). 1994. Murder
in Families. BJS catalog
no. NCJ 143498. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Justice.
Burgess, Adrienne. 1997. Fatherhood Reclaimed:
The Making of the Modern
Father. London: Vermilion.
Cheever, Joan M. 1992. The Year of Litigating
Dangerously. National Law
Journal (October 12): 29.
Children’s Rights Council (CRC). 1992.
Children Taken from Father After He
Testifies Before Congress. Speak Out for Children 7, no. 4:
9.
Christensen, Bryce. 2001. The Strange Politics
of Child Support. Society 39,
no. 1: 63–70.
Clinton, Bill. 1992. Nomination Acceptance Speech
at the Democratic National
Convention, New York, July 16.
Coleman, Grace, Mario Gaboury, Morna Murray,
and Anne Seymour, eds.
2000. 1999 National Victim Assistance Academy. Available at:
http://www.ojp.usdoj.gov/ovc/assist/nvaa99/chap8.htm,
“updated on
Sunday, January 16, 2000.”
Corsi, Jerome. 1984. Judicial Politics. Englewood
Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.
Daniels, Cynthia, ed. 1998. Lost Fathers: The
Politics of Fatherlessness in
America. New York: St. Martin’s.
Dasbach, Steve. 1998. Libertarian Party press
release, February 11.
Department of Justice (DOJ). 1994. Press release,
December 22.
Edin, Kathryn, Laura Lein, and Timothy Nelson.
1998. Low-Income,
Non-residential Fathers: Off-Balance in a Competitive Economy,
in Initial
Analysis. Available at:
http://fatherhood.hhs.gov/ELN/eln98.htm.
Epstein, Elaine. 1993. Speaking the Unspeakable.
Massachusetts Bar
Association Newsletter 33, no. 7: 1.
Fagan, Patrick, and Dorothy Hanks. 1997. The
Child Abuse Crisis: The
Disintegration of Marriage, Family, and the American Community.
Washington,
D.C.: Heritage Foundation.
Father Figures. 1999. Darling Seeks a More Effective
Child Support Agency.
The Times, July 2. Available at: http://fact.on.ca/newpaper/ti99070d.htm.
Fiebert, Martin. 1997. References Examining
Assaults by Women on Their
Spouses/Partners. Sexuality and Culture 1: 273–86.
Franke-Folstad, Kim. 1999. Going after Deadbeat
Parents. Scripps Howard
News Service, August 1. Reprinted at:
http://www.csecouncil.org/news/rockymountain.htm,
accessed October 14, 2003.
Furstenberg, Frank, and Andrew Cherlin. 1991.
Divided Families: What
Happens to Children When Parents Part. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard
University Press.
Gallagher, Maggie. 1996. The Abolition of Marriage:
How We Destroy
Lasting Love. Washington, D.C.: Regnery.
Granju, Katie Allison. 1998. Deadbeat Nation.
Weekly Wire 3 (March 30).
Available at: http://weeklywire.com/ww/03-30-98/knox_feat.html.
Harris, Leslie, D. Waldrop, and L. R. Waldrop.
1990. Making and Breaking
Connections Between Parents’ Duty to Support and Right
to Control Their
Children. Oregon Law Review 69: 689–721.
Health and Human Services Department (HHS).
1998a. Child Maltreatment
1996: Reports from the States to the National Child Abuse
and Neglect
Data System. Washington, D.C.: U.S.
———. 1998b. HHS press releases,
September 28 and December 31.
———. 2000. HHS press release,
September 27.
———. 2003. HHS press release,
May 9.
Hubin, Donald. 1999. Parental Rights and Due
Process. Journal of Law and
Family Studies 1, no. 2: 123–50.
Jacob, Herbert. 1984. Justice in America: Courts,
Lawyers, and the Judicial
Process. 4th ed. Boston and Toronto: Little Brown.
Johnston, James. 1999. The Father of Today’s
Child Support Public Policy.
Fathering Magazine (August). Available at: http://www.fathermag.com.
Kamarck, Elaine Ciulla, and William Galston.
1990. Putting Children First:
A Progressive Family Policy for the 1990s. Washington, D.C.:
Progressive Policy
Institute.
Koplen, Barry. 1999. Minority Report: Virginia’s
Quadrennial Child Support
Guideline Review Commission. Richmond, Va.: Division of Child
Support Enforcement.
Kposowa, Augustine. 2000. Marital Status and
Suicide in the National
Longitudinal Mortality Study. Journal of Epidemiology and
Community Health 54: 254–61.
Lee, Jeff. 2000. Family Blames Justice System
for Pushing Man to Suicide.
Vancouver Sun, March 23, 1.
Levy, Rachael, Bill Gang, and Sandy Thompson.
1997. Court Statistics on
Gender Not Compiled. Las Vegas Sun, January 19. Available
at: http://www.lasvegassun.com/dossier/misc/familycourt/dayonestatistics.html,
accessed October 14, 2003.
Loggins, Kirk. 2001. Child Support Collection
System Sparks Complaints.
Tennessean, June 18. Available at: http://www.tennessean.com/local/archives/01/04/05899347.shtml.
Maguire, John. 2000. Twenty Dollars an Hour
to Visit Your Child. Massachusetts
News, August 2. Available at: http://www.massnews.com/past_issues/2000/8_Aug/20anhour.htm.
Martin, Teresa Casto, and Larry Bumpass. 1989.
Recent Trends in Marital
Disruption. Demography 26: 37–51.
McGrory, Brian. 1994. Fear Invades the Courts.
Boston Globe, October 16, 33.
McHardy, Louis, and Meredith Hofford. 1999.
Final Report of the Child Custody
and Visitation Focus Group, March 1–3, 1999. Available
at: http://www.vaw.umn.edu/FinalDocuments/custodyfin.htm,
“File Last Modified
on: 12/21/99.”
McKee, Mike. 1999. The Deadly Side of Family
Law. California Law Week/Cal/Law.
October 12. Available at: http://fact.on.ca/newpaper/lw990622.htm.
McLanahan, Sara. 1998. Growing Up Without a
Father. In Lost Fathers: The
Politics of Fatherlessness in America, edited by Cynthia Daniels,
85–108. New
York: St. Martin’s.
McMurray, Anne. 1997. Violence Against Ex-Wives:
Anger and Advocacy.
Health Care for Women International 18, no. 6: 543–56.
Meckler, Laura. 2003. Government Handing Money
to States to Promote Marriage.
Seattle Times, May 10. Available at:
http://archives.seattletimes.nwsource.com/cgi-bin/texis.cgi/web/vortex/display?
slug_marry10&date_20030510&query_promote_marriage,
accessed October 10.
Mook, Bob. 1997. Reforms Might Benefit Child-Support
Company. Denver Business
Journal 48, no. 42. Available at: http://denver.bizjournals.com/denver/stories/1997/06/30/smallb3.html.
Morgan, Laura W. 1998. Child Support Guidelines:
Interpretation and Application.
New York: Aspen Law and Business.
Myers, Teresa A. n.d. Case in Brief: Courts
Uphold Criminal Penalties for the Failure to Pay Child Support.
Available at:
http://www.ncsl.org/programs.cyf/Criminalnon.htm,
accessed August 28, 2001.
National Center for Fathering (NCF). 1996. Gallup
Poll on Fathering,
“Fathers in America.” Available at: http://www.fathers.com/research/gallup.html,
accessed December 20, 2003.
National Child Support Enforcement Association
(NCSEA). 2001. Who We Are /
What We Do. Available at: http://www.ncsea.org/about/,
accessed
September 28.
Office of Child Support Enforcement (OCSE).
1999. FY 1998 Preliminary Data
Report. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
———. 2000. Report available
at: http://www.acf.dhhs.gov/programs/cse/pubs/2000/datareport/ch03.html#N91CD,
accessed October 1, 2001.
———. 2001. Report available
at:
http://www.acf.dhhs.gov/programs/cse/davidros.htm,
accessed October 15,
2001.
O’Harrow, Robert. 1999. Uncle Sam Has
All Your Numbers. Washington Post,
June 27, A1.
Olsen, Dean. 1999. State Working on Child-Support
Delays. Aurora Beacon
News, October 16. Available at: http://www.CopleyNewspapers.com/beaconnews/top/a16support.htm,
accessed October 17, 1999.
Page, Robert. 1993. “Family Courts”:
An Effective Judicial Approach to the
Resolution of Family Disputes. Juvenile and Family Court Journal
44, no. 1: 1–56.
Parke, Ross, and Armin Brott. 1999. Throwaway
Dads: The Myths and Barriers
That Keep Men from Being the Fathers They Want to Be. Boston:
Houghton
Mifflin.
Parker, Kathleen. 1999. Deadbeat Dads More Myth
Than Reality. Orlando
Sentinel, January 24. Available at: http://fact.on.ca/newpaper/os990124.htm,
accessed October 11, 2003.
Popenoe, David. 1998. Life Without Father. In
Lost Fathers: The Politics of
Fatherlessness in America, edited by Cynthia Daniels, 33–49.
New York: St.
Martin’s.
Raphaelson, Milton. 2001. Time to Revisit Abuse
Statute. Western
Massachusetts Law Tribune 2, no. 16 (April 18–24): 4.
Rennison, Callie Marie, and Sarah Welchans.
2000. Intimate Partner Violence.
Bureau of Justice Statistics catalog no. NCJ 178247. Washington,
D.C.: U.S.
Department of Justice.
Rogers, R. Mark. 1999. Wisconsin-Style and Income
Shares Child Support
Guidelines: Excessive Burdens and Flawed Economic Foundation.
Family Law
Quarterly 33, no. 1: 135–56.
Rogers, R. Mark, and Donald Bieniewicz. 2000.
Child Cost Economics and
Litigation Issues. Paper presented at the Southern Economic
Association
Annual Meeting, Alexandria, Virginia, November 12.
Rowland, David, Laurie Zabin, and Mark Emerson.
2000. Household Risk and Child
Sexual Abuse in a Low Income, Urban Sample of Women. Adolescent
and Family
Health 1, no. 1: 29–39. Also available at:
http://www.afhjournal.org/docs/010110.asp,
accessed November 7, 2001.
Sarnoff, Susan. 1998. The Institutionalization
of Misinformation: VAWA II.
Women’s Freedom Network Newsletter 5, nos. 3–4:
1, 12–13.
Schroeder, Stephen, and David Sharp. 1992. Fathers
Also Deserve Legal
Protection Against Abuse. St. Petersburg Times, March 2, 2.
Stapleton, John. 2000. “Problem”
Parents Doing Time. The Australian, April 8–9, 26.
Straus, Murray. Forthcoming. The Controversy
over Domestic Violence by
Women: A Methodological, Theoretical, and Sociology of Science
Analysis.
In Violence in Intimate Relationships, edited by X. B. Arriaga
and S. Oskamp.
Thousand Oaks, Calif.: Sage.
Supervised Visitation Network (SVN). 2001. Web
site available at: http://www.svnetwork.net/301Guidelines.html,
accessed October 3.
Tarr, G. Alan. 1999. Judicial Process and Judicial
Policymaking. Belmont, Calif.: West/Wadsworth.
Top 5 Questions Regarding Social Security Number
Collection for Child Support
Enforcement. n.d. National Conference of State Legislatures
(NCSL). Available at: http://www.ncsl.org/programs/cyf/ssnumb.htm,
accessed December 20, 2003.
U.S. House of Representatives. Ways and Means
Committee. 1998. Green Book.
Section 8: Child Support Enforcement Program. Print WMCP:105-7,
DOCID:
f:wm007_08.105. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing
Office.
Walker, Bruce. 1996. Deadbeat Dads? Look Closer.
Christian Science Monitor,
August 16, 18.
Walker, Lenore. 1979. The Battered Woman. New
York: Harper and Row.
Watson, Richard, and Rondal Downing. 1969. The
Politics of the Bench and
the Bar. New York: John Wiley and Sons.
West, Nancy. 2000. Inmate Says Man Who Died
Was Beaten at Jail. New
Hampshire Sunday News, March 5, 16A.
Whelan, Robert. 1993. Broken Homes and Battered
Children: A Study of the
Relationship Between Child Abuse and Family Type. London:
Family Education
Trust.
———. 1995. Just a Piece of
Paper? Divorce Reform and the Undermining of
Marriage. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.
Worden, Amy. 2000. Killing of a Prosecutor Chills
Brethren. Yahoo News, June
12. Available at: http://dailynews.yahoo.com/h/ao/20000612/cr/killing_of_a_prosecutor_
chills_brethren_1.html, accessed June 21, 2000.
|